The GiveWell Blog

Economic empowerment grant: Mistakes, lessons learned, and steps taken

We’ve just published reviews of all of the organizations that applied for our economic empowerment grant. (Note that we previously announced the grant winners here.)

Whenever we publish new charity reviews, we get some push back from charities who aren’t happy that they’ve received a 0-star review.

Before we published our economic empowerment reviews, we sent non-public drafts to the charities so that they could review them for any inaccuracies. In the case of this grant, the push back was both louder and more consistent than we had heard before, and it led us to evaluate our process: what mistakes we had made, what we could do to rectify the situation, and what we should change to handle a process like this better in the future.

The criticism

The main criticisms we received from reviewed organizations were the following:

  1. Your review implies that you’ve conducted an in-depth investigation of our entire organization and concluded that we’re doing a bad job. All you’ve done is determine that our application wasn’t strong enough to win this grant.
  2. We didn’t know that information about our organization would be published on your website. We thought we were participating in a grant process, independent of the general evaluation work GiveWell does.

In some cases these criticisms were valid and spurred us to make changes.

What we’ve changed

Regarding criticism #1, we are generally very careful not to say that we have deemed a charity ineffective. Rather, we say that donors who choose to give to a charity should ask the charity to bear the burden of proof that their activities are accomplishing good. Our approach is to list questions we have about a charity’s activities and say that we have been unable to answer them.

Similarly, we’ve never implied in our reviews that we’ve conducted in-depth investigation of every charity we we rate 0-stars. In explaining why we rely on heuristics in our reviews, we write, “Our research is constrained by practical considerations. Our goal is not to be “perfect” in our assessments but rather to provide better information than donors can find anywhere else.”

Nevertheless, we understand that donors coming to one of our 0-star review pages could misunderstand them and think that we’ve deemed a charity’s programs ineffective. To remedy this, we’ve (a) added explanatory notes at the top of each review to further explain what a 0-star ratings means and (b) tried to specify as clearly as possible the steps we’ve taken for each charity’s review.

Regarding criticism #2, in most cases we feel we were extremely clear about our plans to publish materials.

Most charities we emailed were directed to our main grants page and our FAQ for the grant, both of which prominently discuss our process of publishing our full reasoning and analysis. In addition, many of the applicants (including the majority of those who objected after-the-fact to publication) submitted their applications online, clicking a box on our online application which stated, “I agree that with the exceptions specified in the text box above, all submitted materials are considered public information and will be posted on the GiveWell website.”

That said, there were a handful of organizations that we contacted in non-standard ways, and that can make a reasonable case that we didn’t adequately inform them about public disclosure (at least we can’t establish whether we did). We offered these charities the option not only to have their materials omitted, but to have us not disclose the fact that they applied for this grant from our site.

Note that we never publish an organization’s materials without explicit permission nor do we comment on confidential materials without that permission.

What we’ll do in the future

Two key items we recognized in this process are:

  • It’s important to be completely clear and explicit with organizations about our plans to publish reviews and materials.
  • Our process selects only the very few organizations that can meet our criteria. This means that a 0-star rating is the most likely outcome for an organization we consider. This may provide a disincentive to lesser-known organizations to apply for our grants and invite us to review them (by contrast, more prominent organizations generally appear on our site whether or not they apply).

One idea we’ve had for future grant applications is to create a page, first, for every organization we invite to apply for a grant. This way, the grant process allows organizations to improve their rating; it won’t cause them to receive a rating. It will also make our plans to publish a review crystal clear.

Who needs in-kind donations more: The recipients or the givers?

First it was shoes, then shirts. I don’t have much to add on questions like “Are supplies in fact clogging the roads?” and “Are there in fact people in Africa who don’t wear shirts because they can’t find/afford them?” But to me, the argument against in-kind donations is both simple and general (i.e., it doesn’t depend much on the specifics of the goods):

1. It seems nearly always preferable to sell your unwanted belongings and give the proceeds to charity.

I’m not sure how many (if any) people are “desperate for shirts.” But it does seem that an easy test of whether your old shirt is worth anything to anyone is to ask, “Will someone pay for it?”

This makes it likely that your shirt itself will not get to the poorest people – it will get to whoever pays the most for your shirt. But as long as you give to the proceeds to the best charity you can find, this seems like a good outcome. Imagine that a less-poor person is willing to pay $3 for your shirt; a poorer person wants your shirt but can’t (or won’t) pay $3 for it. That implies that the latter person is better off with the actual $3 (or $3 worth of the best charitable services you can find) than with the shirt.

Of course, if you sell, someone has to pay enough not only for the shirt, but for the costs of shipping and logistics. But that’s part of the point. If there’s no one in the world who will pay enough for your shirt to cover shipping costs, that’s a red flag that you’re looking at a wasteful transaction. Throw out the shirt and give cash. (Again: if someone in Africa is not willing or able to pay the shipping costs to get your shirt, that implies that giving them cash or charitable services equivalent to those shipping costs would be more valued than the shirt.)

The 1 Million Shirts campaign has asked for alternative ways to help people. I think “collect the million shirts, sell them off and give the proceeds to an outstanding charity” is a reasonable proposal.

This is also my understanding of how Goodwill works.

It seems that this argument holds for nearly all in-kind donations. There will be exceptions,* especially where a gift is driven by an acute local need for a particular good. But I would guess that such situations are the exception, rather than the rule, because I don’t think most in-kind donations are driven by the needs of the recipients. That brings me to the next point.

2. Just because your gifts are accepted doesn’t mean they’re wanted.

Good Intentions are Not Enough points to a USAID statement on gifts in kind (PDF). I think it’s an eye-opener, particularly this part:

The American public often … attempts to collect and donate commodities, also referred to as “gifts-in-kind” (GIK). GIK are most often inappropriate for relief programs and harmful to the environment and the local culture. They are expensive to transport, relative to the cost of procuring the same commodities locally. GIK use up scarce resources such as transportation routes, warehouse space, and staff time. They can adversely affect the regional economy by competing with similar commodities available locally. And GIK can contribute to negative images of the United States and its disaster response activities. Despite these problems, USAID often faces significant pressure to assist with or fund shipments of GIK to disaster settings. (Emphasis mine)

I think there is a possible analogy to volunteering. Charities have an incentive – and perhaps also pressure – to accommodate people asking them to give in-kind donations. (We’ve even seen a little of it ourselves; despite the abstractness of our own activities, people come to us asking where to donate leftover drugs or equipment, and it’s never fun to reply with “tough luck.”)

Giving away your goods feels better than taking my above suggestion, because it doesn’t force you to confront the difference between what you paid for the goods and what they’re now worth. (Giving away an old shirt feels better than selling it for $1.) And plenty of organizations are interested in delivering these good feelings. There may also be organizations that simply deliver gifts-in-kind without carefully weighing the shipping costs, logistics issues, etc.

We’ve noted before that much of charity seems set up to serve the donor rather than the recipient. Consider this next time you’re about to give old clothes to people who may not have asked for them (even if it’s through a charity that’s claiming they have).


*For example:

  • Companies/producers can have reasons, relating to price discrimination, to donate the the things they produce. These reasons can apply to a drug company donating drugs, but not to an individual giving away old belongings, so I won’t elaborate on this point here.
  • Sometimes there is an excellent match between what you have to offer and what someone else needs, to the point where (a) the person in need would be close to the highest bidder to buy it; (b) selling rather than donating would create unnecessary middleman/friction costs. (Analogy: if a friend is willing to pay $250 for an old computer that’s worth $300, I’ll take the friend’s offer instead of going through the hassle of selling. On the other hand, if the friend is only willing to pay $50, I’ll sell the computer.)
  • There can be tax advantages to in-kind donations.

If you’re worried about high interest rates, you should be worried about any microfinance institution

I’m very interested in the recent debate over microfinance interest rates (see our response to the NYT article, as well as Te-Ping Chen’s comments at Change.org).

It seems that realizing how high interest rates can be has been a wake-up call to many that microfinance can easily be doing damage as well as good. If someone is paying 150% interest a year, all it takes is some accounting errors for them to end up losing money and getting stuck in debt rather than helping themselves as intended.

But isn’t this concern equally valid for lower interest rates? The same people complaining about excessive interest rates imply that rates 10-30% above the cost of raising capital can be considered reasonable. 10-30% above the cost of raising capital is still significant – it’s more than most Americans pay on their credit card debt – and small losses could be especially risky and damaging to the very poor.

In my view, there is no substitute for asking tough questions about social impact and no excuse for donating to a microfinance charity that can’t answer them.

Room for more funding and fungibility: From the horse’s mouth

We’ve previously argued that the “headline program” a charity uses to raise money may not be the one you’re effectively funding with donations – even if your donations are formally restricted to that program. (See our full series on the topic).

Now the Chronicle of Philanthropy quotes a fundraiser saying exactly the same thing, as a suggestion for charities rather than a warning for donors.

    Nonprofit organizations’ biggest concern with the approach Kiva and DonorsChoose take is that it brings in donations that must be used for a specific purpose, rather than undesignated gifts that can finance anything, including overhead expenses.
    But that’s an accounting issue, not a fund-raising issue, argues Michael Cervino, vice president of Beaconfire Consulting, in Arlington, Va.
    “If you’re already planning as an organization to spend money on A, B, and C programs at a certain level, then there is no reason not to use that program as a poster child for your fund-raising efforts,” he says. “Go ahead and raise that money. You’re going to spend it there.”

Charity reviews vs. movie reviews

Note: I posted most of this post last night as a comment.

There has been some interesting back-and-forth in the comments lately between Laura Deaton and me (see the Should Charity Evaluation be “fair”? thread). Laura seems worried that by issuing ratings and a list of “top” charities, we are implying a level of objectivity and reliability that “overpromises” and can mislead donors. I believe it is a somewhat common concern behind many people’s uncomfortability with the growing interest in charity evaluation.

I think it is helpful to think about how reviews, “top” lists, and evaluations are seen in other domains. For example, movies:

  • Movie reviewers share both quantified, judgmental “ratings” and (some of) the reasoning behind their ratings.
  • Reviews involve substantial judgment calls.
  • Some people read the reviews to get a sense of the reviewers’ values, biases, etc. and decide for themselves how much to weigh them. Some people just look at the ratings.
  • Movie reviewers will sometimes put out a “X best movies of the year” list, even though they haven’t even seen all (or even a substantial portion of) the movies made in a year.
  • Large information providers, including both newspapers and aggregators such as Metacritic/Rotten Tomatoes, will collect the opinions of many movie reviewers in one place and offer them up as a service to people deciding which movies to watch. They will put their name behind the reviews even though they don’t endorse every word of them.
  • The whole system seems to be valuable to a lot of people and to be clearly superior to alternatives such as (a) ratings provided without any reasoning; (b) ratings based on purely objective criteria such as “percent of film budget spent on actors’ salaries”; (c) ratings withheld entirely out of concern for misleading overly impressionable viewers.

Similar systems exist for a lot of consumer decisions.

Any metaphor breaks down and I wouldn’t want this one taken too far. But it seems appropriate for the question at hand, which is whether we are “overpromising” by issuing ratings, evaluations and “top charities” lists. Based on what these terms mean in other domains, I think we are closer to overdelivering.

Added 4/21/2010: I realized after writing this that Tactical Philanthropy made a similar argument in 2007.

No interest rate is too high

Recent coverage of microfinance has had a sharp focus on interest rates, implying some line between “reasonable” interest (associated with “social investment”) and “excessive” interest (associated with “loan sharking”).

    In Nicaragua, President Daniel Ortega, outraged that interest rates there were hovering around 35 percent in 2008, announced that he would back a microfinance institution that would charge 8 to 10 percent, using Venezuelan money …
    Damian von Stauffenberg, who founded an independent rating agency called Microrate, said that local conditions had to be taken into account, but that any firm charging 20 to 30 percent above the market was “unconscionable” and that profit rates above 30 percent should be considered high.
    Mr. Yunus says interest rates should be 10 to 15 percent above the cost of raising the money, with anything beyond a “red zone” of loan sharking. “We need to draw a line between genuine and abuse,” he said. “You will never see the situation of poor people if you look at it through the glasses of profit-making.”

It seems very important that interest rates be transparent, i.e., clearly communicated to and understood by clients. It also is clearly important that there be no coercion, i.e., that clients not be pressured to take loans they don’t want to take. More debatable, but something that we support strongly, are additional measures to assess and improve the client experience, including monitoring overindebtedness, examining dropout rates, etc.

But if/when such things are in place, it is unclear to me on what grounds anyone can complain about interest rates being “too high.” If the terms of loans are clearly communicated, then I see no explanation for why clients would take out loans – unless they feel they have no better alternatives.

What objection can be raised to a 100% interest rate, if the next-best alternative is a 500% interest rate (as I have been told some informal moneylenders charge)? What objection can be raised to a 500% interest rate, if there is no other way for people to get credit? When a loan could result in a sick child’s being treated, or a profitable micro-business, what fee is too high for that benefit?

When MFIs charge more than they need to in order to make a profit, that’s an opportunity for someone else to come in and undercut them. If no one else is coming in, that implies that the costs and difficulty of providing credit in an area may be higher than they appear to an outsider. For an outsider to declare profit margins “too high” strikes me as ungrounded and unproductive, especially when that outsider has not tried to provide credit for less in the same area.

Microfinance exists to improve the lives of the poor. Ideally, then, microfinance institutions would be judged by their effects on people’s lives. Instead, they’re being judged by simplistic financial metrics that crudely attempt to get at the moral uprightness of the organizations. To me that’s a very familiar situation.

I believe the ideal way to evaluate an MFI is to look directly at its impact. When this isn’t possible, proxies for client participation and satisfaction may (debatably) be appropriate. I don’t see any place for universal rules about how much interest can be charged.